Dr Jeroen van der Heijden

Voluntary programs have become increasingly popular in the transition towards a low-carbon economy. They are particularly dominant in the area of low-carbon building development and transformation. Australian examples are Green Star and CitySwitch, both applied throughout Australia; 1200 Buildings in Melbourne; and the Better Buildings Partnership in Sydney.

These programs set requirements to low-carbon building development and transformation that reach well beyond mandatory requirements as laid down in the National Construction Code. In committing to these programs, property developers, owners and users have access to exclusive rewards. For instance, Green Star provides exclusive branding opportunities through its certificates and the Better Buildings Partnership allows its participants to engage closely with the City of Sydney.

Over the last four years I have studied 60 voluntary programs for low-carbon buildings in Australia, India, Malaysia, the Netherlands, Singapore and the United States. Earlier this year I brought together my research findings in a book manuscript that is due for publication later in 2016. In this article and a series of coming posts that follows I will present an exclusive preview of the main findings of this research project.

In short, today I address why it is so difficult to regulate and achieve low-carbon buildings and why governments, firms and other organisations and individuals have moved to voluntary programs. In the next article I will address programs in areas such as forestry, organic food and environmental management, and the lessons the buildings sector may draw from it. Then I will write three individual articles that each present findings on “popular” types of voluntary programs for sustainable buildings: certification and classification (like Green Star), knowledge generation and sharing programs (like CitySwitch and the Better Buildings Partnership) and funding programs (like 1200 Buildings).

The second group of posts will first draw conclusions from the programs I’ve studied in Australia, the Netherlands and the US. These are not hopeful: in general these programs have a marginal impact on decarbonising the built environment –marginal at best. I will then open up to the programs studied in India, Malaysia and Singapore. This will highlight why in the Global South it is even more complicated and risky to rely on voluntary programs for low-carbon buildings than it is in the Global North.

Throughout the posts it will become clear that I am not too hopeful about voluntary programs for low-carbon building development and transformation, but I still see value in them.

I will argue, however, that we need to rethink their position in the larger regulatory and governance framework for decarbonising the built environment. This will be the topic of the last post in this series. In it I will particularly draw lessons from the few positive examples I have encountered – these include NABERS in Australia, Green Mark in Singapore, Retrofit Chicago in the US and the Better Buildings Partnership in Sydney.

Just one note of caution: in these posts I give a taste of what the book will have to offer. I will leave out many details and academic debates that I do discuss in the book. In these posts I focus particularly on the main lessons learnt from the study that are relevant to policymakers and practitioners.

Why is it so complicated to regulate low-carbon buildings?

That is a tough question and does not allow for an easy answer – I answer it in an earlier book – but three main problems stand out.

First, regulating low-carbon buildings is a battle on two fronts and this is not often well understood. Buildings are a key source of resource consumption (energy, raw materials, water) and waste production (construction waste, carbon emissions). Technology is available to considerably reduce resource consumption and waste production of buildings.

For governments it is, however, difficult to mandate the use of such technology. The democratic process of policymaking requires many checks and balances, and thus a long time, before a new requirement makes it from the drawing table into the NCC.

But not only is the slow development process problematic. A main problem with building and construction regulation is that new requirements often only apply to new construction work and major renovations. Existing buildings are normally exempted from new mandatory requirements.

Yet, the high levels of building related resource consumption and waste production come from today’s buildings. However sustainable and low-carbon our future buildings may be: if we don’t improve the current building stock it will be of little avail.

Second, the construction and property sectors are highly fragmented and characterised by a very “long tail”. Many other sectors are characterised by “winner takes all” markets, but not the property and construction sectors. Think for instance of supermarkets in Australia. There are two dominant players that have a market share of more that 80 percent – Coles and Woolworths. If a government can convince these two players to change their behaviour, it will see change in 80 percent of the supermarket market.

Now think of the construction and property sectors: There are thousands and thousands of developers, contractors, sub-contractors, architects, engineers, and so on. And there are millions and millions of buildings owners, landlords and tenants. In these sectors it is of limited help to focus on a small number of “large bad guys” to solve the lion’s share of the problem.

Behaviour

Third, building regulation and construction codes traditionally focus on objects and not behaviour. It is, however, the inefficient way we use our buildings that requires high levels of resource consumption and results in much waste. With a slight change of behaviour households can easily reduce up to 20 per cent of their energy consumption and office tenants up to 50 per cent.

We find it perfectly normal to have our behaviour regulated when it comes to speed limits or even (not) smoking in public premises. But we do not want governments to interfere in how we use and behave in our homes, offices and other buildings. Imagine the public outcry that would result from a government restriction on heating in winter (say, 19 degrees centigrade as you can wear an extra jumper when you’re cold) and cooling in summer. Such a mandate would, also, be impossible to enforce.

A shift to voluntary programs for low-carbon buildings

Acknowledging these problems with mandatory building regulation and construction codes, governments around the world have begun to search for alternative and complementary instruments to govern the transition to a low-carbon built environment.

Voluntary programs are a specific type of innovative governance instruments that have been implemented since the early 1990s. Voluntary programs are highly comparable to mandatory regulation. They introduce a set of standards for their participants to meet. They often have an enforcement mechanism in place to assess compliance with these standards. And they penalise non-compliance – and reward compliance.

There are, however, some important differences between voluntary programs and mandatory building regulation and construction codes. First is that they are non-mandatory. No one is, in principle, required to participate in a voluntary program. People and firms participate in these because they expect specific benefits from doing so.

This then is the second important difference: the rewards from participating in a voluntary program are exclusive to program participants. The benefits of, say, Green Star (marketability of the sustainability credentials of a building) can only be obtained from having Green Star certification.

These rewards come in different forms. Marketability under Green Star, direct interaction with government under the Better Buildings Partnership, information on how to reduce energy consumption in offices under CitySwitch, and access to funding for building retrofits under 1200 Buildings (I will discuss all these programs in more depth in the posts that follow).

The third important difference is that these instruments are often developed and implemented in collaboration with industry and civil society stakeholders – or are sometimes developed without all too much government involvement at all. They are, also, often developed to target a specific problem experienced by a specific group of people or firms.

Expectations of voluntary programs for low-carbon buildings

These differences are expected to come with a number of benefits over mandatory building regulation and construction codes. Voluntary participation is expected to result in higher levels of compliance than with mandatory regulation and codes. The assumption is that people seek the exclusive benefits that come with participating in a program, and will do what is required to achieve these benefits.

The positive rewards that come from complying with a voluntary program are also expected to improve compliance. People and firms are not penalised for not complying, but rewarded for compliance. The range of rewards is, further, expected to be attractive to a wide range of potential participants: those that seek to market the credentials of their buildings, those that seek information, those that seek funding, and so on.

The involvement of industry and civil society stakeholders ensures that their expertise and knowledge of the construction and property sectors is used in the development and implementation of these programs. They have much deeper knowledge of the sectors and built environment than government bureaucrats. Including this knowledge may help to come to programs that are effective and efficient in realising a transition to low-carbon buildings.

Finally, voluntary programs are expected to address the problem of “one size fits all” building regulation and construction codes. Mandatory building regulation and construction codes are often too blunt to deal with specific local issues. Voluntary programs are, however, often developed to address a local problem as experienced by local stakeholders – often by involving them in developing the program. Think of them as “tailored” programs. This is expected to result in programs that are more effective in solving local problems than what mandatory and general requirements can achieve.

Too good to be true?

In light of the unsustainable amount of resources required to construct, maintain and use buildings, as well as the wastes resulting from these activities, a shift to a low-carbon built environment is necessary. Traditional building regulation and construction codes developed and implemented by governments have not been able to accelerate this transition. Voluntary programs come with high expectations on doing so.

One can – and I think should – question whether such programs are perhaps too good to be true. The achievements of these programs are often lauded, but to date little systematic, international and large-scale research has been carried out to understand their value and limitations for low-carbon building development and transformation. Over the next weeks I will publish a number of blog posts to do exactly that. Stay tuned. You will likely be shocked by some of my findings.

Dr Jeroen van der Heijden is senior research fellow at Australian National University and associate professor at the University of Amsterdam. Through his research he aims to improve local, national and international outcomes of urban governance on some of the most pressing challenges of our time: climate change, energy and water use, and a growing and increasingly urbanising world population.

Join the Conversation

4

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

  1. You need to look at the SDAPP (Sustainable Design Assessment in the Planning Process) program used by 11 Melbourne Councils, and rapidly growing. The SDAPP program was started in 2007 by Moreland and Port Phillip Councils. It is voluntary and asks planning applicants to complete a ESD assessment of their proposal using the free rating tool STEPS and SDS. Larger developments also require a report outlining the ESD features. The tools will be superseded in the next few months by the BESS tool. https://bess.net.au/
    All of this is under the umbrella of CASBE (Council Alliance for a Sustainable Built Environment)and all the member councils meet every 2 months to discuss various issues. The SDAPP program has been in place in Darebin Council since 2007 and I have worked here since 2012. It is very successful at reducing energy and water use and incorporating passive design early in the process. It applies to all development of 5 or more units and over 100sq.m but there are lower triggers in other councils.
    You can contact the CASBE coordinator, Natasha Palich at the MAV (Municipal Association of Victoria). casbe@mav.asn.au

  2. Thanks Jeroen. Great reflection. I think there are many parallels with voluntary schemes encouraging environmental sustainability in farming (governments won’t regulate so encourage voluntary participation through programs such as Landcare but there’s little evidence to suggest these are making much difference).
    So, why not put a price on energy (carbon) that transforms voluntary action into meaningful outcomes?
    David

    1. Thanks David. Good question. Putting a price on energy would likely help a lot, but doesn’t seem to fare well with policymakers and their voters. Voluntary programs like these are a political and popular reality, which is why I have been studying them for a while. Hopefully my findings will help developing better policy programs–or at least make people a little more critical about this type of voluntary programs and what their administrators tell us about their performance.